Opinion for the Court filed by Circuit Judge ROGERS.
ROGERS, Circuit Judge:
In 1994, the Federal Communications Commission established a 45 MHz spectrum cap on commercial mobile radio services ("CMRS") that limited the total amount of cellular, broadband personal communication service ("PCS"), and specialized mobile radio
I.
CMRS encompasses different types of spectrum put to a variety of uses. It includes all mobile services commercially offered to the public that are connected to the telephone network, such as cellular phone service, paging, mobile data, mobile satellite, and other wireless services. See generally Second Report & Order, 9 F.C.C.R. 1411, 1422-42, paras. 30-70 (1994). CMRS is composed of cellular, PCS, and SMR spectrum. Within each of these categories, spectrum is described as narrowband (using less than 5 MHz of spectrum) and broadband (using more than 5 MHz of spectrum). The narrowband/broadband distinction rests in part on whether it is possible to accumulate enough spectrum to provide voice communication. Entities can use CMRS spectrum to provide voice-to-voice service, such as cellular phone or dispatch service, as well as data-only service, such as paging.
In 1994, the Commission adopted changes to the technical, operational, and licensing rules "to establish regulatory symmetry among similar mobile services." Third Report & Order, 9 F.C.C.R. 7988, 7992, para. 1 (1994). These changes included imposition of a 45 MHz cap on the total amount of cellular, PCS, and SMR spectrum an entity could have in any geographic area. Id. at 7999, para. 16. The Commission justified the cap "as a minimally intrusive means of ensuring that the mobile communications marketplace remains competitive and retains incentives for efficiency and innovation." Id. at 8100, para. 238; see also id. at 8104, para. 248. The spectrum cap would prevent entities from accumulating spectrum and thereby "precluding entry by other service providers." Id. at 8101, para. 240. Rejecting a "case-by-case" approach, the Commission described the cap as a "bright line test" that would provide certainty and ease the Commission's "administrative burden." Id. at 8104-05, para. 250.
The changing nature of the market was key to determining the scope of the cap. The Commission first observed that services provided on the CMRS spectrum were converging. See id. at 8020, para. 56. The Commission explained that the various mobile services shared the common purpose of servicing customers who "need to communicate electronically on a real-time basis (or virtually real-time basis) while they are `on the move.'" Id. at 8021, para. 58. Technological innovation influenced market trends that would allow various CMRS licensees to compete. The Commission observed that voice communication providers had the capacity to provide data services and that data service providers had the option, with reconfiguration and accumulation of spectrum, to provide voice services. See id. at 8026-35, paras. 69-77. The Commission concluded that "trends in the CMRS marketplace ... illustrate a strong potential for further competition among all CMRS services." Id. at 8035, para. 77.
In defining the scope of the cap's coverage, the Commission decided to exclude all terrestrial narrowband radio services. See id. at 8111, para. 267. Because it was "highly
The Commission reconsidered the cap following a remand from the United States Court of Appeals for the Sixth Circuit, in a case in which the 45 MHz cap itself was not at issue but the attribution and eligibility rules were. See Cincinnati Bell Tel. Co. v. FCC, 69 F.3d 752 (6th Cir.1995).
Shortly thereafter, BellSouth Wireless requested a waiver of the spectrum aggregation limit.
The FCC's response was two-fold. First, in a letter dated August 29, 1996, the Wireless Telecommunications Bureau denied BellSouth's request for a waiver. See Letter re: BellSouth Wireless, Inc. Request for Waiver in Auction No. 11, 11 F.C.C.R. 9970 (1996). The Bureau stated that BellSouth's assertion that RAM does not compete with real-time two-way voice service was based on a misconception about the underlying purpose of the CMRS spectrum cap; the cap in fact arose out of concerns about excessive horizontal concentration and market barriers. See id. at 9971. Additionally, while covered versus non-covered SMR was a significant distinction in some contexts, it was not so in the spectrum aggregation context. See id. The Bureau also invited BellSouth to seek to divest itself of the .5 MHz of SMR spectrum if it wished to bid for two 10 MHz bundles of PCS or to pursue its argument as part of a request for reconsideration of related orders. See id. at 9972.
The Commission affirmed the Bureau's denial of a waiver, rejecting BellSouth's arguments that the rule was in effect unwaivable and that the Bureau had not given a "hard look" at the waiver application. See Memorandum Opinion & Order, 12 F.C.C.R. 14031 (1997). The Bureau had considered the facts proffered, balanced them and the purposes underlying the CMRS spectrum aggregation limit, and noted the availability of alternative ways that BellSouth could obtain relief. The Commission also declined to reconsider the
Id. at 14038-39, para. 12. Further, the Commission explained that it distinguished covered and non-covered SMR in rules that only affected two-way voice services interconnected to the public switched network. See id. at 14040, para. 14. With regard to spectrum aggregation, the Commission explained that it
Id.
II.
In its petition and appeal to this court, BellSouth makes two principal contentions: first, that the spectrum cap rule is overbroad, extending beyond its purpose to assure competition in voice communications, and second, that the Commission has adopted a virtually unwaivable rule and failed to give the waiver request a "hard look." Just as narrowband is exempt from the cap, BellSouth contends, SMR dedicated to data-only services should be as well. Essentially, BellSouth maintains that the only purpose of the rule was to prevent the exercise of market power in voice services, not non-voice data-only services. This purpose is clear, BellSouth maintains, from the fact that (1) the Commission exempted narrowband spectrum, which is used for non-voice services; (2) in conducting its market analysis following the remand from the Sixth Circuit, the Commission defined the market and other terms such that the only economic justification for the cap is to deter excess spectrum concentration and market power in the voice communication market; and (3) the Commission has repeatedly distinguished between covered SMR (voice services) and non-covered SMR (non-voice services) in regulatory decisions on the ground that the services did not compete in the same market. Finally, BellSouth contends that by failing to identify the standards for evaluating waiver requests, the Commission has engaged in the type of tautological reasoning rejected by this court in WAIT Radio v. FCC, 418 F.2d 1153, 1158 (D.C.Cir. 1969)(WAIT I). See Pet'r's Br. at 19 ("In sum, the [Commission's] failure to cure the overbreadth of its rule, coupled with its unwillingness to entertain a clearly de minimis waiver was unreasoned decisionmaking.").
A.
Under the Administrative Procedure Act, the court must "hold unlawful and set aside agency action" that is "arbitrary, capricious, an abuse of discretion, or otherwise not in accordance with law." 5 U.S.C. § 706(2)(A) (1994). Thus, in reviewing decisions of the Commission, the court
Melcher v. FCC, 134 F.3d 1143, 1152 (D.C.Cir.1998) (citations and quotation marks omitted). Although the arbitrary and capricious standard of review is deferential, the court will "intervene to ensure that the agency
Challenging the denial of a waiver is likewise not an easy task because an applicant for waiver bears the heavy burden on appeal to show that "the Commission's reasons for declining to grant the waiver were so insubstantial as to render that denial an abuse of discretion." Turro v. FCC, 859 F.2d 1498, 1499 (D.C.Cir.1988); see also Thomas Radio Co. v. FCC, 716 F.2d 921, 924 (D.C.Cir.1983).
B.
Central to BellSouth's challenge to the spectrum cap is its view that the cap has one goal: to foster competition in mobile voice-to-voice communication. With this goal as a basis for regulation, BellSouth contends that the FCC irrationally included within the CMRS spectrum cap SMR spectrum dedicated to data services, which, BellSouth maintains, can have no impact on the competitive nature of the voice communication market. Yet the Commission has taken a different position, maintaining that it was concerned with the effect of CMRS spectrum aggregation on the development of market power and on the competitive market for mobile services as a whole in light of the predicted potential for various services along that spectrum to converge. The general cap on CMRS spectrum thus reflects concern for the CMRS market generally. The Commission has predicted that mobile services will converge because of consumer demands and providers' technological capabilities to offer various voice and data services. Contrary to BellSouth's characterization, which either ignores or discredits other concerns and objectives that resulted in the spectrum cap, the Commission has consistently maintained that general spectrum aggregation will enable an anticompetitive exercise of market power absent a cap on the amount of spectrum one entity can hold. So viewed, BellSouth's contentions about the effects of excluding SMR spectrum used to provide data-only services falter. To exempt SMR spectrum "dedicated" to data-only use, as BellSouth proposes, would not prevent an entity from accumulating spectrum and in the process, would allow that entity to preclude others from obtaining it. The same entity could subsequently decide to use that spectrum to provide voice services, a change over which the Commission has limited control. Further, even the provision of data-only services would have an impact on the market because mobile voice and data services are marketed to the same consumers and, under the Commission's theory, they are converging services.
BellSouth maintains, however, that the economic analysis conducted by the Commission in response to the remand by the Sixth Circuit in Cincinnati Bell demonstrates that the Commission is only concerned with the market for voice communication. For purposes of its economic analysis, the Commission defined the product market as "mobile two-way voice communications service," and competitors as "licensees for cellular service and broadband PCS, and the largest interconnected SMR." Report & Order, 11 F.C.C.R. 7824, 7904 (1996). For purposes of its rulemaking, however, the Commission has viewed the market as the CMRS spectrum as a whole, not merely the provision of certain services on that spectrum. It was this construction of the market that controlled when the spectrum cap was first established in the 1994 Third Report and Order. While its HHI analysis focused on voice-to-voice communication, thus indicating that voice communication was high on the Commission's list of concerns, there is nothing to suggest that the Commission abandoned its more general concern in responding to the Sixth Circuit's direction for a "reasoned basis" and "an economic
Since its Third Report and Order, the Commission has focused on the CMRS spectrum as a whole. It has predicted that the services provided on the CMRS spectrum will converge. Those service providers who are not already actual competitors are certainly potential competitors. See 9 F.C.C.R. at 8003, para. 27. As a cellular licensee, BellSouth qualifies as a competitor. Once an entity qualifies as a competitor, the Commission is concerned with how much spectrum that entity accumulates. In its view, market power hinges on the amount of spectrum an entity holds. CMRS spectrum is a finite resource and is also exclusive in that whatever one entity holds cannot be held by another. Moreover, all the spectrum included under the cap could potentially be used to provide voice services. It follows that identification of voice communications as the product market would not undermine the force of the Commission's conclusion that a 45 MHz cap is needed to prevent the exercise of market power.
Furthermore, the fact that the Commission has distinguished between voice and data uses of SMR spectrum in other regulatory decisions
For example, in CMRS Resale Order, the Commission decided that only covered SMR providers would be required to comply with the cellular resale obligation, which prohibits cellular carriers from restricting resale of their services. See 11 F.C.C.R. at 18,466, para. 19. The Commission concluded that non-covered licensees, who offer narrowband-type services, do not compete substantially with cellular and broadband PCS providers, and wished only to regulate providers with "significant potential to compete directly with cellular and broadband PCS providers in the near term." Id. Similarly, in CMRS Roaming Order, the Commission extended the manual roaming rule only to "all CMRS licensees competing in the mass market for real-time, two-way voice services" including covered SMR providers. 11 F.C.C.R. at 9470, para. 12. With regard to non-covered licensees, the Commission concluded that because they "do not compete substantially with cellular and broadband PCS providers," these providers would not be covered. Id. at 9471, para. 14. In other proceedings, the Commission has continued to recognize the covered/non-covered distinction in determining how carriers can use their spectrum. See E911 Order, 11 F.C.C.R. at 18716, para. 81; Number Portability Order, 11 F.C.C.R. at 8355, para. 4 & 8433-34, para. 156. Recently the Bureau permitted Motorola to transfer ownership interests in certain telecommunications holdings to the American Mobile Satellite Corporation, see ARDIS Order 13 F.C.C.R. at 5193-94, paras. 18-21, and the Commission decided that any CMRS system not offering two-way switched voice service would be exempt from the requirements of number portability, see Telephone Number Portability, CC Docket No. 95-116 RM 8535, FCC 98-275 (released Oct. 20, 1998).
The Commission can reasonably and rationally distinguish between regulating spectrum already held and regulating the accumulation of spectrum. As the Commission
Ultimately, BellSouth's contentions fail because of its restricted view of the Commission's goals and purposes that directly contradicts the Commission's analysis. Absent a showing that SMR spectrum dedicated to data is virtually identical to the "narrowband" spectrum excluded from the cap, which BellSouth failed to make in its briefs or at oral argument, BellSouth cannot demonstrate that the Commission acted arbitrarily when it drew the line between SMR and narrowband spectrum and included SMR in the 45 MHz cap. The Commission's reliance on the converging nature of the CMRS market is sufficient to justify its inclusion of all SMR in the spectrum cap. Similarly, its explanation for the exclusion of narrowband PCS from the cap, namely that it is virtually impossible to accumulate sufficient spectrum, is adequate.
C.
BellSouth's attack on the denial of its request for a waiver of the spectrum cap fares no better. BellSouth focuses on the fact that granting its waiver would have involved a de minimis exception to the cap, and maintains that the RAM spectrum was "incapable" of being used for voice communication.
The "hard look" requirement assures that a general rule serving the public interest for a broad range of situations will not be rigidly applied where its application would not be in the public interest as, for example, where an applicant "proposes a new service that will not undermine the policy" served by the rule. WAIT Radio v. FCC, 418 F.2d 1153, 1157 (D.C.Cir.1969) (WAIT I). Therefore, when an agency receives a request for waiver that is "stated with clarity and accompanied by supporting data," such requests "are not subject to perfunctory treatment, but must be given a hard look." Id. While an agency must consider the relevant factors, see KCST-TV, Inc. v. FCC, 699 F.2d 1185, 1191-92 (D.C.Cir.1983), in explaining the denial of a waiver request, "the agency is not required to author an essay for the disposition of each application. It suffices, in the usual case, that we can discern the why and wherefore." ICBC Corp. v. FCC, 716 F.2d 926, 929 (D.C.Cir.1983) (quotations omitted); see also P&R Temmer v. FCC, 743 F.2d 918, 932 (D.C.Cir.1984).
From the outset, the Commission has characterized the spectrum cap as a "bright line" rule. Third Report & Order, 9 F.C.C.R. 7988, 8104-05, para. 250 (1994). A spectrum cap, unlike many other regulations, might actually require a bright-line rule to be effective. Moreover, refusal to grant a waiver to BellSouth does not necessarily mean that the Commission has created a "no-waiver" policy. The Commission has consistently stated that the de minimis nature of the excess above the cap, standing alone, would not justify a waiver. At oral argument, the Commission explained that, hypothetically, if a market was not adequately served by providers, the Commission would consider permitting a carrier already in the market to accumulate spectrum above the cap if it seemed that no competitor would enter the market and use otherwise fallow spectrum. In other words, even a bright-line rule may give way to special circumstances warranting an exception in the public interest. Such circumstances do not arise, however, where, as here, a waiver applicant seeks to circumvent a rule merely because it does so only minimally.
The Commission reasonably determined that the Bureau gave BellSouth's waiver request a "hard look," explaining that the cap was designed to prevent aggregation of spectrum as well as spur competition and that BellSouth had alternative ways to avoid exceeding the cap. Because BellSouth did not explicitly present a de minimis argument in its waiver petition, the Bureau had no reason to address this argument in its letter ruling.
Accordingly, we deny BellSouth's petition and affirm the Commission's denial of the waiver request.
FootNotes
Cincinnati Bell, 69 F.3d at 764 (citations omitted).
Comment
User Comments