EMMERT, J.
This is an appeal from a judgment entered for failure of appellant to amend and plead over after a demurrer had been sustained to its complaint.
Appellant, a Michigan corporation, alleged by its complaint it manufactured carpet sweepers, which had thereon its trade-mark "Bissell Carpet Sweeper Company," which were sold in open competition in Indiana "with merchandise in the same general class produced by others"; that appellee was engaged in the retail business in the city of Indianapolis; that appellant had entered into voluntary contracts with certain retailers including H.P. Wasson & Co., pursuant to the Indiana Fair Trade Act which established minimum prices for its carpet sweepers throughout the state; that the appellee did not execute any "such contract to establish such minimum resale prices," but that prior to the filing of the complaint appellant gave written notice to the appellee that such contracts were in existence, but that appellee wilfully and knowingly offered for sale and did sell the carpet sweepers at less than the minimum prices established by appellant's contract, and that the sale did not come within any of the exceptions provided for in § 5 of the Fair Trade Act.
The Fair Trade Act, ch. 17 of the 1937 Acts (§ 66-301 to § 66-309, Burns' 1951 Replacement), is limited to commodities using a trade-mark, brand or name, of a producer or distributor, and sold in free and open competition with commodities of the same general class produced or distributed by others. Section 66-302, Burns' 1951 Replacement, declares valid contracts between a seller and a buyer, or a series of contracts between successive sellers and buyers for sale at wholesale or retail, requiring the ultimate retailer to contract not to sell the commodities at less than the fair trade price established by the original seller. A could sell to B with B contracting he would not sell at retail below the price fixed by A, or with B contracting that if he sold to retailer C he would require of C a contract not to sell at retail below the price fixed by A, or if C sold to D for resale, he would require of D a similar provision for the benefit of A, who would fix the minimum retail price. Thus, the fair trade price required of the ultimate retailer could be established by contract, or a series of subsequent contracts for the benefit of the first seller establishing the fair trade price. The ultimate retailer would be bound because of his contract, and not because a statute said he should be bound when he did not consent.
The price fixing authorized by this section is somewhat similar to the factual situation in Dr. Miles Medical Co. v. Park & Sons Co. (1911), 220 U.S. 373, 31 S.Ct. 376, 55 L.Ed. 502. The Court, in an opinion by
It is within the power of the General Assembly to change the common law rule in Indiana, and to except fair trade price fixing by contracts between buyers and sellers from the various provisions of the restraint of trade acts of this state.
The Miller-Tydings Act of 1937 (15 U.S.C.A. § 1) amended the Sherman Anti-Trust Act and the Federal Trade Commission Act to make lawful price fixing contracts in interstate commerce if they were lawful in intrastate commerce. In Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Distillers Corp. (1951), 341 U.S. 384, 71 S.Ct. 745, 95 L.Ed. 1035, it was held price fixing by compulsion was not validated by the Act. The Court clearly noted the distinction by the following language:
The appellant Bissell bases its cause of action on § 6 of the Fair Trade Act, which states:
The complaint specifically alleges the appellee Shane was not a party to any contract to fix the retail price. It fails to allege from whom Shane purchased the sweepers or when they were purchased. For all that was alleged, Shane could have purchased them in Michigan where fair trade price fixing is illegal. Shakespeare Co. v. Lippman's Tool Shop Sporting Goods Co. (1952), 334 Mich. 109, 54 N.W.2d 268; Argus Cameras v. Distributors (1955), 343 Mich. 54, 72 N.W.2d 152. Appellant's position is that wilfully and knowingly selling and offering for sale Bissell's sweepers at prices less than fixed by Bissell after notice of the contracts
We are not at liberty to substitute our judgment for that of the General Assembly as to whether price fixing is good or bad for the economic life of the state. Conceivably, in a time of depression the benefits might outweigh the disadvantages, while the converse may be true in a time of prosperity or inflation. But the Indiana Constitution on separation of powers and the vesting of the right to enact laws in the General Assembly have the same meaning whatever may be the business or economic conditions of the State.
The right to fix a utility rate, which is price fixing for the service, is a legislative act. State ex rel. Evansville etc. Lines v. Rawlings (1951), 229 Ind. 552, 99 N.E.2d 597, and authorities therein cited. After the Legislature has enacted that the rates be just and reasonable, it can delegate to an administrative commission the duty of finding as a fact what charge would be just and reasonable, but the commission does not make a law. The law operates on the facts found by the commission under proper standards and after a hearing. The rate is legislative in character because it makes a rule for the future, and binds both the utility and the users of its services whether they consent or not. Prentis v. Atlantic Coast Line Co. (1908), 211 U.S. 210, 29 S.Ct. 67, 53 L.Ed. 150; Chicago, etc. R. Co. v. Railroad Comm. (1911), 175 Ind. 630, 643, 95 N.E. 364; In re Northwestern Indiana Tel. Co. (1930),
A fortiori, § 66-306, Burns' 1951 Replacement, is broad enough to vest a legislative power to fix prices in private persons. But the Constitution says "The Legislative authority of the State shall be vested in the General Assembly ..." Article 4, Section 1. The power to legislate or to exercise a legislative function cannot be delegated to a non-governmental agency or person. Tucker v. State (1941), 218 Ind. 614, 697, 698, 35 N.E.2d 270.
Section 66-306, Burns' 1951 Replacement, goes far beyond the codes of fair competition authorized by the National Industrial Act of 1933 (15 U.S.C. § 703). In Schechter Corp. v. United States (1935), 295 U.S. 495, 55 S.Ct. 837, 79 L.Ed. 1570, 97 A.L.R. 947, a Code of Fair Competition for the Live Poultry Industry in the Metropolitan Area of New York was held unconstitutional because Congress could not abdicate its law-making power to a trade association or to the President. No standards were prescribed for any trade, industry or activity. It laid down no rules for administrative fact finding. Mr. Justice Cardozo noted this was "delegation running riot." Section 6 of the Fair Trade Act has no requirement for any governmental action by any public officer to establish a coercive price binding on any seller covered by the act.
The decision in Old Dearborn Co. v. Seagram Corp. (1936), 299 U.S. 183, 57 S.Ct. 139, 81 L.Ed. 109, 106 A.L.R. 1476, has been cited in other states for the proposition that fair trade acts do not attempt legislative price fixing by private persons. Section 1 of the Illinois Act was similar to § 2 of the Indiana Act and authorized parties to contract for vertical price fixing from the original seller to the ultimate retailer. Concerning this part of the Illinois Act the court said:
In the Dearborn Case, supra, the court carefully excluded any determination of the validity of the Illinois statute under the Fourteenth Amendment in a case where the retailer purchased the goods in ignorance of the fair trade contract.
It is within the power of the Legislature to declare such inducement to breach a contract unfair competition and actionable. In so far as § 66-306, Burns' 1951 Replacement, authorizes this, it is constitutional. The duty breached was not one created by the legislative act of two parties to a contract fixing a price binding upon every retailer of the goods whether or not he knew he was inducing a breach of the contract, or whether or not he purchased the goods from one under no contract obligation to require a fair trade contract from the retailer. Under the particular facts in the Old Dearborn Co. case the court held the Old Dearborn Co. could not complain that the Fourteenth Amendment prohibited the injunction against it.
But in the appeal at bar the complaint and the contracts fail to show anything more than attempted
It is not necessary here to decide what might be proper subjects for legislative price fixing under the Indiana Constitution. And in view of the reasoning of this opinion, it becomes unnecessary to determine whether the construction of § 6 of the Fair Trade Act
By the Fair Trade Act, the General Assembly has removed the ban of the common law, as well as the acts concerning restraints of trade and monopolies which prohibited vertical price fixing by agreements or contract between buyers and sellers, but he who seeks to take advantage of the Fair Trade Act will have to base his action on a breach of his contract, or a breach of contract made for his benefit, or on a tortious inducement of a breach of such a contract. This the complaint did not do, and the demurrer was properly sustained.
Judgment affirmed.
Bobbitt, J., concurs specially with separate opinion in which Achor, C.J., and Arterburn, J., concur.
Landis, J., dissents with opinion.
CONCURRING OPINION
BOBBITT, J.
I concur in the result of Judge Emmert's opinion and with his reasoning as it pertains to the fixing of prices by contract between buyers and sellers who are parties to such contracts.
However, I do not concur in his reasoning pertaining
The following statement appears in Judge Emmert's opinion:
I do not want to be understood as concurring in, or lending any support to, the inference which must, in my opinion, necessarily be drawn from this language, that the Legislature has the power to delegate to a State Agency, Board or Commission the authority to fix the price of carpet sweepers or any other commodity of trade or commerce on the open market.
In my opinion the Legislature does not have the power to fix the price at which carpet sweepers may be sold in Indiana, and it must follow that it cannot lawfully delegate such authority to a governmental agency, even with proper "safeguards and procedural due process." Dept. of Financial Institutions v. Holt, etc. (1952), 231 Ind. 293, 303-304, 108 N.E.2d 629.
It is, of course, true, as stated in the opinion, that the fixing of a utility rate is a legislative act; and that the Legislature can, and does, delegate to an administrative commission the authority to fix public utility rates within the bounds of certain standards set by the Legislature. However, it does not follow that the source of such power also furnishes the authority to fix standards for, and delegate to, an administrative commission the authority to fix prices for general commodities of trade and commerce.
The Legislature derives its power to fix and regulate
The supervision and regulation of public utilities by the Legislature is designed to supply the missing element of competition which protects the public from excessive charges in competitive businesses. Public Service Commission v. Indiana Bell Telephone Co. (1955), 235 Ind. 1, 130 N.E.2d 467, 481. Such reason for supervision and regulation (price fixing) is not present where there is open competition in a business such as the manufacture and sale of carpet sweepers.
The right of an individual to engage in a lawful business and to fix the price at which he disposes of his own property is a part of his inalienable right to "liberty and the pursuit of happiness," and is guaranteed by both our State and Federal Constitutions.
The lack of constitutional power of the Legislature to fix prices by law or delegate such power must be, in this case, distinguished from the right of the Legislature to broaden the contracting powers of individuals and corporations, thus permitting them to enter into multiple agreements to fix prices. At common law such contracts were against public policy because they were considered monopolistic and in restraint of trade. The Legislature determines the public policy of the State, and in the exercise of this power it may, by statute, modify or change the rule at common law and enlarge the scope of contractual powers of individuals and corporations.
Achor, C.J., and Arterburn, J., concur.
DISSENTING OPINION
LANDIS, J.
I cannot agree with the opinion of the court written by Emmert, J., which holds the Fair Trade Law of Indiana is an unconstitutional delegation of legislative power and an infringement of due process in violation of Article 4, § 1 and Article 1, § 12 of the Indiana Constitution.
The opinion, in my view, means that we have one theory of separation of powers and due process under the Federal Constitution and a different and distinct doctrine of separation of powers and due process under the Indiana Constitution.
The language employed in the two constitutional documents is identical for our purposes, the Constitutions of the United States and of Indiana providing respectively as to the separation of legislative powers: "All legislative powers ... shall be vested in a congress,"
Any application of the Dr. Miles case, supra, to the case before us has therefore been removed by statute.
The next case relied upon in the opinion of the court has similarly been rendered ineffective and inapplicable by a subsequent statute. It is Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Corp. (1951), 341 U.S. 384, 71 S.Ct. 745, 95 L.Ed. 1035 (hereinafter referred to as the first Schwegmann case), which decided that Fair Trade contracts with non-signer provisions were in violation of federal anti-trust laws, since the Miller-Tydings Act of 1937 providing exemption from anti-trust laws did not apply to non-signer contract provisions. This statutory deficiency of the Miller-Tydings Act was shortly afterwards remedied by the McGuire Act of 1952
The unquestioned landmark case in the federal courts on the constitutionality of the Fair Trade is Old Dearborn Co. v. Seagram Corp. (1936), 299 U.S. 183, 57 S.Ct. 139, 81 L.Ed. 109, 106 A.L.R. 1476, which involved the Fair Trade Act of Illinois.
In that case appellee Seagram, a Delaware corporation, was a wholesale dealer in alcoholic beverages in Illinois. Appellant operated four retail liquor stores in Chicago, but did not purchase any of the whiskey in controversy from appellee. Appellant's charter powers included sales at both wholesale and retail.
In the Old Dearborn case the challenge was directed against § 2 of the Illinois act which provided that wilfully and knowingly advertising, offering for sale, and selling any commodity at less than stipulated in any contract made under the act, whether the person doing so is or is not a party to the contract, shall constitute unfair competition, giving rise to a right of action in favor of anyone damaged thereby. In Old Dearborn there was no contractual liability shown on the part of appellant, and the U.S. Supreme Court in a unanimous
The majority opinion in the case before us attempts to distinguish the facts of Old Dearborn from the case at bar.
The evidence in Old Dearborn indicated the Old Dearborn Company purchased some of the whiskey in controversy from persons under Fair Trade contract with others, and also purchased whiskey from persons not signatories to such contracts.
The observation of the majority in the case before us that, although the U.S. Supreme Court "did not take note of it," Old Dearborn in fact "was committing a tort by inducing a breach of a distributor's contract to Seagram Corporation" is an attempted limitation of Old Dearborn upon a basis that did not sufficiently impress the U.S. Supreme Court for it to express itself on the subject. Not only did Old Dearborn procure whiskey from contract signers and non-signers, so as to preclude any possibility of an induced breach of contract as to the latter, but even as to the former we cannot arbitrarily say there was a tort committed by Old Dearborn. Before we can conclude ex parte that Old Dearborn committed torts in inducing breaches of contract not at issue in that case, we should note that there are many situations where a defendant may be
The majority's attempted limitation of Old Dearborn to cases of contractual liability or inducing a tort is a strained construction of the case and entirely unwarranted.
The N.R.A. Schechter case
The next case in the federal courts involving Fair Trade after Old Dearborn is Schwegmann Bros. v. Calvert Corp., supra (the first Schwegmann case), which has been previously treated. It was superseded by the McGuire Act passed in 1952 (excepting Fair Trade agreements from federal anti-trust laws as to both signers and non-signers), and thereafter the second
As stated in the second Schwegmann case at pp. 791, 792 of 205 F.2d:
In connection with the test of whether an illegal fixing of prices had occurred, the court cited the case of Nebbia v. New York (1934), 291 U.S. 502, at p. 539, 54 S.Ct. 505, at p. 517, 78 L.Ed. 940, at p. 958, 89 A.L.R. 1469, at p. 1484, where the court said:
In determining whether there was an arbitrary, discriminatory, and unlawful price fixing or price control under the Fair Trade Act in question, the court in the
I do not believe this is the place for a prolonged discussion of whether Fair Trade appears to us to be good or bad for the economic or social life of the state.
Briefly stated, however, the proponents of Fair Trade contend that although it might appear at first blush that price cutting by a retailer is not harmful to a manufacturer, there is respectable opinion to the contrary — that the maintenance of a fair margin of profit encourages the retailer to offer a standard product of good quality to the public rather than to endeavor to substitute a sub-standard, or inferior product in an effort to meet price-cutting competition; that this, in time, affects the public.
The opponents of Fair Trade say that while in the bleak days of the 1930's there might have been some
The opponents of Fair Trade, including some text writers and law journal contributors, ask, however, that we enter the argument of economics and decide in the light of present-day conditions against the wisdom of Fair Trade legislation, and thus hold it unconstitutional. However, I do not believe we can have one constitution in fair weather and an entirely different constitution in foul. This court does not sit as a super-legislature to weigh the propriety of legislation, nor to decide whether it expressly offends the public welfare. The legislative power has limits, but state legislatures have power to experiment with new techniques and use their own standard of the public welfare so long as specific constitutional prohibitions are not violated.
And as to legislative policy, we should note that while numerous changes have been made in Congressional
Before concluding this opinion I think we should also observe that the U.S. District Court for the Southern District of Indiana has recently held the Fair Trade Act of Indiana with non-signer provisions is valid and constitutional as against the contentions that it violates due process and is an unlawful delegation of legislative powers,
And not only is it the law in the federal courts that the Fair Trade Acts are not invalid as violating due process or being an unlawful delegation of legislative power in restricting prices, but the rule is followed in a majority of state courts.
I would reverse the judgment.
NOTE. — Reported in 143 N.E.2d 415.
FootNotes
"First. In respect of the due process of law clause, it is contended that the statute is a price-fixing law, which has the effect of denying to the owner of property the right to determine for himself the price at which he will sell. Appellants invoke the well-settled general principle that the right of the owner of property to fix the price at which he will sell it is an inherent attribute of the property itself, and as such is within the protection of the Fifth and Fourteenth Amendments. Tyson & Brother v. Banton, 273 U.S. 418, 429; Wolff Co. v. Industrial Court, 262 U.S. 522, 537; Ribnik v. McBride, 277 U.S. 350; Williams v. Standard Oil Co., 278 U.S. 235; New State Ice Co. v. Liebmann, 285 U.S. 262. These cases hold that, with certain exceptions, which need not now be set forth, this right of the owner cannot be denied by legislative enactment fixing prices and compelling such owner to adhere to them. But the decisions referred to deal only with legislative price fixing. They constitute no authority for holding that prices in respect of `identified' goods may not be fixed under legislative leave by contract between the parties. The Illinois Fair Trade Act does not infringe the doctrine of these cases." Old Dearborn Co. v. Seagram Corp. (1936), 299 U.S. 183, 191, 192, 57 S.Ct. 139, 81 L.Ed. 109, 106 A.L.R. 1476.
Comment
User Comments